The
defunding of many offices within the US federal government dedicated to
gathering data about production of goods is one of the reasons it took
longer than it might have to increase production of personal protective
equipment during the Covid pandemic © AFP via Getty Images That’s
industrial policy folks. It used to be that all developed nations with
the exception of the US engaged in it, albeit quietly. Now, it’s back in
public vogue, and even Americans are keen on it. It has always been
central to the Biden administration, but now, according to a senior
administration official I interviewed recently, business leaders are
coming to Washington and asking for a signal in the noise of
deglobalisation — should they be in Vietnam, Mexico, South Carolina?
Should they put investment into clean technology or biotech, or both?
They are also looking for increased public support for more domestic
production in the wake of the semiconductor industry’s
multibillion-dollar boost. But what is industrial policy exactly? And how should it be used — if at all — in the US? Let’s
start by understanding that the contours of industrial policy differ
depending on the country. Command and control states like China
explicitly pick winning sectors, and even companies, and lavish public
incentives on them for better or worse. They also engage in mercantilism
and protectionism of all kinds to ring fence and support local markets.
European countries like France support “national champions” (think
Airbus) and Germany is well-known for its co-determination model of
corporate governance in which the public sector, private sector and
labour all play a role in how companies operate. But
the US is different. The country has for the past half a century been
run like a company — lean and mean. As long as consumer prices were
falling, it didn’t matter how many industries were lost or jobs
outsourced and/or displaced by technology. That’s now changing (see my Monday column
on the death of trickle-down economics) for all sorts of reasons, from
national security and environmental concerns to technological and
demographic shifts that favour more domestic production and labour. Both
the right and the left in particular are trying to figure out what the
contours of more government directed economic policies should be. How do
we make industrial policy something that supports equitable growth,
rather than simply becoming a boondoggle for already wealthy
corporations? This
past Friday, I spoke at a Roosevelt Institute event “Progressive
Industrial Policy: 2022 and Beyond”, which was a terrific deep dive into
this topic (see the live stream of the event, here). Below are five of my top takeaways: We
need more data. Over the past couple of decades, most of the offices
within the federal government dedicated to gathering data about
production of goods have been defunded. That’s one reason it took longer
than it might have to increase production of personal protective
equipment during the Covid pandemic. We didn’t even know how much stuff
we were producing, or who was doing it. Basic data gathering doesn’t
cost that much money, and having this kind of information about what is
or can be manufactured in the country would be a great starting point
for shaping better policy (on that score, we should also roll back the
Donald Trump-era budget cuts of the Office of Financial Research, which
gathers similar info on financial markets). Environmental
sustainability and good jobs are critical economic organising
principals. We’ve always lived in a world in which incentivising gross
domestic product growth was priority one. But in the future, managing
climate change and issues of income distribution (at both the national
and global level) will probably be the top priorities. So policymakers
will have to ask whether their prescriptions support lower use of fossil
fuels, the transition to clean energy, and middle-class job creation. Manufacturing
isn’t simply a “fetish for keeping white males with low education in
the powerful positions they are in”, as the Peterson Institute for
International Economics economist Adam Posen put it, rather shockingly,
at the Cato Institute recently. Rather, it’s a building block for
place-based economics (particularly in the era of high-tech
manufacturing, which blends services and technology in deeper ways than
old factory line jobs did, it’s the core of a strong and diverse
economy). By the way, I continue to be shocked at how little mainstream
economists get how businesses are run, or indeed how geopolitics works.
Perhaps the economics profession itself is a way to keep white males
with high education in the powerful positions they are in. Services
matter, too. Growth is people plus productivity. Getting more
minorities and women into the labour market is crucial for growth, and
since most of them are in service sectors, you have to bake that into
industrial strategies. That’s why unions are focused on organising home
healthcare workers, for example (amazing fact: these workers were cut
out of the social security system years ago and are fighting for
pensions; Washington just became the first state to award them). Implementation
is hard. Neoliberalism has died hard because it was simple — a share
price is the only metric of success, government should just step out of
the way. Getting more voices in the room is tougher — but that doesn’t
mean we shouldn’t try.
|